Related Literature Sample Clauses

Related Literature. We apply the theory of Bayesian games originally developed by Harsanyi (1967, 1968a,b) to model the interactions between the power plant and the distributor. Bayesian games have been applied to the electricity markets to model the suppliers’ bidding processes in which each power plant’s marginal cost is private information. Such a game has been analyzed in various market conditions by Ferrero et al. (1998), Xxxxxxxxxxxx et al. (2002), Li and Xxxxxxxxxxxx (2005), and Xxxxxxx (2005), among others. Xxxxx¸csu and Puller (2008) analyze bidding processes in which contract positions are private information. Unlike previous works, in this paper information asymmetry comes from the fact that the plant’s status cannot be directly observed by the distributor, and the unit-contingent power purchase agreement introduces incentive conflicts into the system. Several economics papers on contract theory are related to our work. For example, Laffont and Martimort (2002, Section 3.6) discuss an adverse selection problem with audits and costly state verification. The costly audit allows the principal to detect an untruthful agent’s report and impose penalties. The Revelation Principle still applies, and under the truth-revealing mechanisms, punishments are never used, but the existence of punishments reduces agent’s incentive to lie and, hence, reduces informational rents. Xxxxxxxxxx and Png (1989) and Reinganum and Wilde (1985) apply the adverse selection problems with costly state verification to insurance and taxation. In contrast to these papers, our analysis is focused on a particular contract form commonly seen in practice. Because of the restriction on the contract set, instead of invoking the mechanism design approach (as in Xxxxxxx 1981, 1979, Guesnerie and Laffont 1984), we find the equilibrium of the Bayesian game directly. Within the unit-contingent contract space, we show the truth-revealing mechanism is not necessarily optimal. Our work shares some similarities to the economics literature on contracting with costly state verification (e.g., Xxxxxxxx 1979) and literature on incomplete contracts (e.g., Xxxxxx and Sapping- ton 1991, Boot et al. 1993, Bernheim and Whinston 1998) in that by allowing flexibility to act to one party, a better equilibrium outcome can be achieved. However, there are a number of essential dif- ferences between our work and this literature. For instance, Xxxxxxxx (1979) and related economics literature on bonding and insurance are concerne...
AutoNDA by SimpleDocs
Related Literature. There is a wide choice of related literature concerning the aggregation of SLAs. Approaches of close relationship to our work can be roughly categorized in three areas whose boundaries blur to some extent. Models which aggregate the SLOs of single SLIs in a mathematical way are introduced in (Xxxxx and Xxxxxxxx 2007; Xxxxxx et al. 2004; Xxxxx et al. 2008). Models which cover the PROSA characteris- tic of being a document, that is, they provide a framework for building a single document out of a set of SLA documents (SLAs of the single services invoked by one BP) are discussed in (Xxxxxx and Xxxxxxxx 2008; Xxxxxxxxx et al. 2007; Xxxxxxx 2000). Finally, (Xxxx et al. 2002; Xxxx et al. 2008) elaborate models which validate the SLOs on BP level by means of simulations. The related work delivers some valuable insights into two main aspects of the in hand research domain. On the one hand approaches to technically aggregate SLIs and on the other hand ap- proaches which deal with the SLA characteristic of being a document that is aggre- gating the single SLAs to one document. But some highly interesting and impor- tant issues are not covered. Presented models are bottom-up-approaches. Looking at the motivation our approach is customer-oriented. That is a customer who wants to facilitate his business processes by IT-services delivers the objectives concerning the SLOs of the PROSA to the provider(s). Therefore these objectives have to be drilled down to a deep level of technical services – a top-down- approach. Whereas a bottom-up-approach deals with the attributes of technical services and aggregates them bottom-up which is not suitable for our addressed issues. Additionally the mentioned approaches do not cover both aspects custom- er-orientation and provider-methodology. They are all driven by the providers’ perspective. In summary, current approaches deliver first contributions to the do- main of SLA aggregation. But they do not cover the customer as well as the pro- vider perspective in an adequate way. Especially the motivated customer orienta- tion is not represented as much as required.
Related Literature. Sequential P4D deals with potential challengers share the logic developed by Xxxxxxxx (1984), but with deterrence investment substituted with P4D deals and licensing an authorized generic (AG). Indeed, the strategy of launching an AG via a P4D deal with a challenger is similar to earlier studies that focus on licensing as a strategy to maintain market leadership and/or deter entry. For instance, Xxxxxxx (1984) shows the conditions where the incumbent licenses its production technology to a potential entrant in exchange for terminating research into competing for better technology, while Xxxxxxx (1990) and Xxxxxxx (1994) provide models where the incumbent licenses either the weaker competitor or a competitor from outside of the industry, so as to crowd the market and discourage stronger competitors from entering. By contrast, in our paper, the generic with the AG license is the de facto strongest competitor to the brand as it enters before other generics and grabs the first mover advantage. Additionally, instead of a license being introduced prior to the potential competitor incurring entry costs, in our paper the license is issued and AG launched only if the next potential entrant has incurred an entry cost (i.e., litigation cost), and is successful. A significant economic and legal literature builds around theory of harm and focuses on the legality of pay-for-delay deals (Xxxxxxx, 2003a, Xxxxxx and Xxxxxxx, 2005, Xxxxxxx and Xxxxxxx, 2008, Xxxxx, 2012). Under Xxxxxxx’x antitrust welfare criteria – that a settlement should leave the consumers at least as well off as the ongoing patent litigation – a payment that exceeds the expected litigation costs of the licensor is sufficient to establish that consumers lose from the settlement (Xxxxxxx, 2003b, Elhauge and Xxxxxxx, 2012). In line with this reasoning, several authors have argued that pay-for-delay settlements should carry a presumption of per se anticompetitive behavior (see for instance, Xxxxxxxxx et al., 2003, Bulow, 2004, Xxxxxxx and Xxxxxxx, 2004, Xxxxxxxx, 2009). Others have pointed out that while the theory of harm is useful, it has limitations and cannot be applied directly to the more complex agreements between the parties, or that P4D deals can in fact be pro-competitive in some situations, and hence such deals should not be per se illegal (Xxxxx, 2002, Xxxxxx and Xxxxxxx, 2004, Xxxxxx et al., 2010, Xxxxxxxx, 2013). For instance, Xxxxxxx and Xxxxxxx (2015) critique Xxxxxxx and Xxxxxxx (2012) and...
Related Literature. Sequential P4D deals with potential challengers are similar to the logic developed by Xxxxxxxx [1984], but with deterrence investment substituted with P4D deals and licensing an AG. In fact, the strategy of launching an AG via a P4D deal with a challenger, as discussed in this paper, is similar to earlier studies that focus on licensing as a strategy to maintain market leadership and/or deter entry. For instance, Xxxxxxx [1984] shows the conditions where the incumbent licenses its production technology to a potential entrant in exchange for terminating research into competing or better technology, while Xxxxxxx [1990] and Xxxxxxx [1994] provide models where the incumbent licenses either the weaker competitor or a competitor from outside of the industry, so as to crowd the market and discourage stronger competitors from entering. Yet, despite these similarities, important differences exist between our paper and previous studies on licensing. In our paper the generic with the AG licence is the de facto strongest competitor to the brand as it enters before other generics and grabs the first mover advantage. Additionally, instead of a license being introduced prior to the potential competitor incurring entry costs, in our paper the license is issued and AG launched only if the next potential entrant has incurred an entry cost, (i.e., a litigation cost) and is successful. Several studies have documented the impact branded manufacturers have when they launch their own generic or an authorized generic (AG) via a third party on independent generic entry. Xxxxxx [2003] argues that authorized generics deter independent generic entry in intermediate sized markets (and “probably” in other markets as well) while Reiffen and Xxxx [2007] show that authorized generic entry may deter independent generic entry in small and intermediate sized markets only and raise the long run prices by 1-2%. Xxxxxx et al. [2007] argue that the effect of authorized entry on independent generic entry and ultimately on consumer welfare is likely to be small but still positive. However, Xxxxxx [2015] reports that early authorized entry has no impact on the likelihood of generic entry. As documented in a report by the Federal Trade Commission [FTC, 2011b, pp.17-18], authorized generics can be launched by the branded firm itself (in-house) or via third parties but require expertise in generic marketing. This is because whereas brand name drugs are typically marketed to physicians and consumers e...
Related Literature. 3.1 Stability and Renegotiation Proofness Although our notion is not one of renegotiation-proofness, its connection to various theories of renegotiation-proofness is evident. First, both our theory and the notions of renegotiation proofness allow for coalitional deviations, although renegotiation proofness restricts coalitional deviations to those of the grand coalition. Secondly, the notion of stable agreements is defined by applying the notion of stability that was originated by xxx Xxxxxxx and Xxxxxxxxxxx (1944) and extended by Xxxxxxxxx (1990); the theories of renegotiation-proofness exhibit various attempts to apply the notion of sta- bility. As Xxxxxxxxxx (1992) wrote “... the renegotiation literature (as well as the new approach suggested by Xxxxxxxxx (1990)) is returning to the internal and external consistency ideas suggested by xxx Xxxxxxx and Xxxxxxxxxxx (1944). For example, (weak) renegotiation proofness of Xxxxxxxx and Xxx (1989) and Xxxxxxx and Xxxxxx (1989) imposes a version of internal stabil- ity (stronger than ours) while Xxxxxx’x (1991) Pareto perfect equilibrium imposes also external stability in addition to the same internal stability as Xxxxxxxx and Xxx (1989) and Xxxxxxx and Xxxxxx (1989). However, the notions of renegotiation proofness can be criticized for tak- ing Pareto criterion too far as discussed in the introduction. They stipulate that the grand coalition will renegotiate and abandon a punishment when- ever there is a Pareto dominating equilibrium available even though the later equilibrium may rely on punishments that are as severe. Implicitly, a deviat- ing player counts too heavily on renegotiation. Our notion explores a natural extension of the uncertainty aversion on the part of players embedded in the notion of subgame perfection. Our notion can be viewed as the weakest notion that accounts for coalitional deviations. For two-player games, it is easy to see that an efficient (weakly) renegotiation-proof45 equilibrium also belongs to the set of stable agreements for N. However, we do recognize the importance and relevance of renegotiation in formalizing notions stronger than ours. In a future project, we shall extend our analysis to account for credible renegotiation.
Related Literature. This article fits within two lines of economic literature. First, economic models of learning set the background for the incorporation of sequential information into beliefs. Bayesian learning in particular ocassions an acknowledgment of the psycho- logical work on the topic. Second, committee voting inspires a natural extension of the model. This section offers a brief review of the relevant literature.
Related Literature. ‌ This paper draws from and contributes to three areas of prior and ongoing research. One area is the literature that explores potential uses of electronic ledger technology to improve economic outcomes. Xxxxxxxx (2020) (34) discusses myriad potential use-cases where outcomes can be improved when financial objects are appended to programmable participant accessible ledgers. This paper adds the example of the repo market to list of applications. Another area is the literature on the shadow banking sector where, in the aftermath of the financial crisis there has been an effort to map the system, of which the repo market is an important part. Economists at the Federal Reserve and the Department of Treasury Office of Financial Research have published a large number of studies that draw on new administrative data collected from financial firms as a result of the Xxxx-Xxxxx legislation.5 Finally, this paper contributes to the ongoing discussion of reforms to increase the capacity of banks to intermediate the repo market. In response to the disruptions that occured in the repo market in September 2019 and in the cash treasuries market in October 2014 and March 2020, there have been proposed regulatory reforms to reduce the likelihood and severity of future disruptions. Xxxxxx (2018) (13) and (2020) (14) and the Group of Thirty (2020) (14) have notably contributed to this reassessment exercise. We contribute to this literature by proposing a very different approach to improving repo market performance and resiliency.
AutoNDA by SimpleDocs
Related Literature. The idea of using ISAs to finance professional education was first proposed in Xxxxxxxx and Xxxxxxx (1945). Nerlove (1975) points out that participants’ behavioral responses (e.g., moral hazard) to ISAs may challenge the viability of risk-pooling ISAs. We show ISAs may not only be viable but also be more attractive than student-loan financing for both universities and students even in the presence of moral hazard. Grout (1983) shows ISAs are appealing to students when job market is highly uncertain and students are risk averse. We show ISAs maybe attractive even when students are risk neutral. Xxxx (1998) focuses on how human-capital investments are financed and shows that if the investments are financed by contingent loans, which carry interests only if the borrower is employed, optimal investments can be obtained in a wide range of situations. We explicitly consider the role of student’s financial difficulty in the case of unfavorable employment outcome and show that ISAs may not be optimal from the university’s and social-welfare perspective, particularly if the student’s financial difficulty is small. As such, our findings challenge the Xxxxxxx (2006) conclusion (on the basis of the extent literature) that ISAs are in general welfare increasing compared to either bank loans or up-front fees. We contribute to the literature on ISAs by explicitly considering students’ financial difficulties and generating new insights including about when ISAs may be welfare enhancing. A large stream of literature following Xxxxxx (1964) examines implications of consumers’ borrowing and repayment decisions for investment in human capital (more generally, in projects with notably poor collateral).7 Xxxxxxxx and Xxxxxx (2005) show income inequality contributes to increased consumer borrowing to finance the purchase of durable goods. We show that a higher income inequality can lead universities to primarily focus on high-income 7Please refer to Xxxxxxx and Xxxxx-Xxxxxxx (2016) for a comprehensive overview of literature on student loans and repayments. students for profits by raising tuition. In the context of collateral-free loans, Xxxxx and Xxx (2012) show lenders use peer-lending decisions to infer creditworthiness of borrowers. In our model, the creditworthiness of students is decided by the offer of admission to the university. Xxx, Xx, and Xxxxx (2018) develop a theory model to explain near-zero default rates even in the absence of any collateral in informal lending ma...
Related Literature. In this section I will first take a quick glance at the video game industry and then go through scholarly works that have been done on the subjects of dynamic incentives and consumer investment. By reviewing the literature, I hope to spot the gap in the current literature and describe the contribution of my work.
Related Literature. Multiple streams of research inform my investigation into gamification. Prior work on loyalty programs, gambling and goals each discuss how gamification may influence consumer behavior. In what follows, I will identify key findings from these literatures that help explain how consumers should respond to gamification programs that combine dynamic incentive schemes with outcome uncertainty.
Time is Money Join Law Insider Premium to draft better contracts faster.